
After-work drinks in decline outside London, peers told
Mr Swinney, director of the Centre for Cities think tank, was among various experts giving evidence to a special House of Lords committee set up earlier this year to examine the impact of remote and hybrid working in the UK.Last month, the think tank published research on the pre and post-pandemic spending patterns of city-centre workers in pubs and bars around their places of work, by comparing credit and debit card data from 2019 and 2024.The analysis showed that during that period, the share of weekly spending in pubs in central London on Fridays fell, whilst on Thursdays it rose, making it the most most popular night of the week.But a similar pattern was not seen in the data for nine other large British cities, including Glasgow, Liverpool, Bristol, Newcastle and Sheffield.Surveys have shown Friday has become the most popular day for office workers to work from home, with attendance during the middle of the week returning to more similar levels to before the Covid pandemic.
'Shift to weekend'
Explaining the spending data to peers on Thursday, Mr Swinney said that in London "the Friday night drink hasn't so much gone away, it's just shifted to a Thursday"."But when we looked at other large cities, that wasn't the case," he added."It appeared from the data that we have that the post-work drink has reduced in those other places."Actually the shift seems to go into the weekend, which seems to be workers coming in from a leisure perspective, rather than going out after work".The data analysed by the Centre for Cities showed that 32% of weekly pub spending in big cities outside London now takes place on a Saturday, suggesting workers are more likely to return on weekends to socialise than in the capital.
Supermarket spending
Elsewhere in the session, Mr Swinney said a decline in city-centre spending since the rise in remote and hybrid working had not been matched by an equivalent rise in spending on "local High Streets"."That might have happened a little bit, but certainly not to the extent that people were suggesting [during the pandemic]," he told the committee.He added that suburban supermarkets had "probably been the biggest winner" from the shift in spending patterns since Covid.He said more flexible working patterns had led to some immediate benefits for workers, including reduced travel cost and more flexibility.But he added it could be "two, three, ten years down the line" before the long-term impact on economic productivity could be properly assessed.
Hashtags

Try Our AI Features
Explore what Daily8 AI can do for you:
Comments
No comments yet...
Related Articles


The Independent
32 minutes ago
- The Independent
Why zero-hours contracts could be here to stay in new blow to workers' rights
A proposed crack down on zero-hour contracts in the workplace have suffered a setback today. Flagship plans by the Government to halt zero-hour contracts in the workplace have been scuppered by peers in the House of Lords. The House of Lords backed by 264 to 158, majority 106, a move to change the legal requirement for an employer to offer guaranteed hours to an employee's right to request the arrangement. Peers went on to inflict a further blow on the Labour front bench in supporting by 267 votes to 153, majority 114, a measure to exempt employers from having to make a payment to a worker if a shift was cancelled with at least 48 hours' notice. The defeats came as the Employment Rights Bill, which has already been through the Commons, continued its passage through the upper chamber. The changes made by peers to the draft law paves the way for a parliamentary tussle, known as 'ping-pong', where the legislation is batted between the two Houses until agreement is reached. The proposed workers' rights reforms also introduce new restrictions on 'fire-and-rehire' processes when employees are let go and then re-employed on new contracts with worse pay or conditions. In addition, the Bill strengthens trade unions and gives workers certain 'day one' rights, such as sick pay, paternity leave and the right to request flexible working. Proposing his alternative to the proposed zero-hours provision, Liberal Democrat Lord Goddard of Stockport acknowledged the need to tackle the 'exploitative' use of the practice that left workers in 'precarious employment circumstances'. But he added: 'That said, our amendment reflects that shared objective, while offering a more practical and balanced view. 'The amendment changes legislation from an obligation to offer guaranteed hours to a right to request them. 'Furthermore, it maintains that when a such request is made, the employer must grant it.' He added: 'Our amendment seeks a fair balance, protecting workers from exploitation while preserving the flexibility which is crucial for many industries to function.' But opposing the move, Labour peer Baroness Carberry of Muswell Hill, a former assistant general secretary of the Trades Union Congress, warned: 'I very much fear that it undermines the purpose of the Bill, which is trying to deal with the problem of zero-hours contracts.' She said: 'What the amendment doesn't take account of is the imbalance of power in workplaces and the characteristics of employees who are working on zero-hours contracts.' Arguing those on zero-hours contracts were 'the least empowered workers', Lady Carberry added: 'So the right to request guaranteed hours in those circumstances is not a real right at all. 'And then how many of those workers, vulnerable as they are, might come under pressure not to press for guaranteed hours 'This formulation of the amendment leaves open the path to some of those worst employers to make sure that they don't end up offering guaranteed hours to workers on zero-hours contracts.' However, Tory shadow business minister Lord Sharpe of Epsom said: 'It makes no sense to require employers to offer guaranteed hours to employees who don't want them. 'The Government appears to misunderstand or simply disregard the autonomy of the individual worker. 'Imposing this administrative burden, especially on small employers, to calculate and offer guaranteed hours where they are neither wanted nor needed, is an unnecessary and unavoidable cost. 'We therefore strongly support the right to request amendment proposed by Lord Goddard which better respects worker choice and employer flexibility.' Responding, business minister Baroness Jones of Whitchurch said: 'We believe the duty to make a guaranteed offer should lie with the employer. 'This is the best way to ensure that all qualifying workers benefit from the right guaranteed hours when they want them. 'If a worker on an exploitative zero-hours contract had to request the guaranteed outcome, they may feel less able to assert their right to those guaranteed hours, and they would lose out as a result. 'It's quite right to highlight the imbalance of power in the workforce for these individuals, and this is particularly true when workers take up a new job.' She added: 'A right to request model could create undesirable barriers, making it especially difficult for vulnerable workers on exploitative zero-hours contracts to access their right to those guaranteed hours, especially as many workers are younger and often in their first job. 'As the Bill is currently drafted after receiving an offer from the employer, qualifying workers will be empowered to make a decision based on their individual circumstances. 'If a worker wants to retain their zero-hours contract, as many will, they can do so by rejecting the offer.'


The Independent
37 minutes ago
- The Independent
Why wouldn't a wealth tax work in Britain?
Not so long ago, when Labour was in opposition and still popular, there was no question of introducing a wealth tax. Yet today, influential figures such as former leader Neil Kinnock and ex-first minister of Wales Eluned Morgan, and some trade unions, are advocating just such a change. More tellingly, ministers simply refuse to rule out a wealth tax as they might have done before. The latest to do so is the transport secretary, Heidi Alexander, who was asked if the topic had come up at last Friday's cabinet away day and enigmatically replied: 'Not directly.' Teased at Prime Minister's Questions on the subject, even Keir Starmer couldn't bring himself to issue a flat denial. Some wonder if a wealth tax could actually happen... What did Labour promise? There's nothing in the manifesto to rule out a wealth tax, but in an interview in August 2023, Rachel Reeves was unequivocal: 'We have no plans for a wealth tax. We don't have any plans to increase taxes outside of what we've said. I don't see the way to prosperity as being through taxation. I want to grow the economy,' she said, adding: 'We won't be doing that. It's a denial.' And as recently as her spring statement in April, she declared: 'We're not interested in a wealth tax. Our priority is to grow the economy, and that's the way that you make working people better off and secure better public finances.' What does the left want? It's usually stated as a 2 per cent levy on assets – property, shares, art etc – owned by individuals in excess of £10m. For example, someone worth £12m would pay a levy of 2 per cent of £2m – a bill of £40,000. It could be paid immediately, or deferred to disposal (or death). Figures such as Richard Burgon, a left-wing MP who believes in it, says it would raise 'up to' £24bn. What does the chancellor say? As little as possible at the moment, suspiciously sticking to the 'working people' line (though some working people are worth £10m, and more). No denials, then. What are the arguments for a wealth tax? It's said that the country shouldn't balance the books on the backs of the most vulnerable, and that fairness demands that those with the broadest shoulders bear the greatest burden. Recent controversies about disability benefits and children with special needs have heightened the arguments. It's also true that wealth in the UK is undertaxed compared with income, and that we live in an unequal society, at least by some European standards. Economists warn about what might happen as wealth accumulates through inheritance over the very long run. As Thomas Piketty puts it: 'Inheritance will eventually matter a lot pretty much everywhere – as it did in ancient societies. Past wealth will tend to dominate new wealth, and successors will tend to dominate labour earners.' The present debate about 'intergenerational fairness' is one artefact of this phenomenon. And against a wealth tax? It has been tried, and failed. Comparable nations such as France, Germany, Switzerland and Norway have more or less abandoned wealth taxes, or found them to be unproductive. Almost half a century ago, a previous British Labour government issued a green paper on a proposed wealth tax, but then the chancellor, Denis Healey, concluded it would be impractical and too costly to administer. The wealthy have always found ways to avoid such taxes and protect their assets, while the super-rich simply skip the country altogether. Tax expert Dan Neidle judges: 'The idea that we can do something different is naive. It's arrogant to think that we in the UK can achieve a holy grail everyone else has been too stupid to find.' What wealth could be taxed? An uncomfortable truth is that the easiest wealth to tax would be the most politically difficult – and arguably, the least fair: homes and pension pots belonging to individuals worth far less than £10m, and who would fall into the category of 'working people' that Labour has pledged to look after. After all, you can't take the house in which you live and move it overseas. And many of the assets in question will have been taxed already. Any government that tried to tax a capital gain on a principal private residence would place itself in opposition for a generation. What are the practical problems with a wealth tax? Imagine obliging everyone to declare an accurate value for the property (and everything else) they own, along with how much they paid for it, or when it was inherited and its value at the time, and then employing HMRC officials to undertake checks and audits on such a mass of information. Should theoretical, unrealised gains be index-linked to allow for inflation? Any allowance for, say, renovating a derelict building? What counts and what doesn't? Wedding rings? A classic car? The family business? And how about offsetting capital losses on bad investments or failing companies? It would take years to process. What could Reeves have her eye on? It could be large, uncrystallised capital gains on assets such as rental properties, bonds, pension pots and shares at death, which mostly escape inheritance tax (IHT). It would basically be an extension of inheritance tax, itself a deeply unpopular levy (albeit few pay, and the thresholds are generous). Anything else? Capital gains on virtually anything except a main home are already taxed, as are pension pots in certain circumstances, and there isn't that much room left to hike these tax rates. Stamp duty on mansions has already been increased substantially, and of course 'non-dom' status was abolished by the previous government. The 'family farm tax' – the removal of the IHT exemption for agricultural property – is another recent, and unwelcome, change for many. They've even specifically taxed private jets. Beyond a certain level, heavy disincentives to save and invest start to kick in, which would be bad for the economy. For example, Neidle shows how this can depress investment: 'A 2 per cent wealth tax doesn't sound like much, but for someone earning an 8 per cent return on their assets, that plus existing dividend tax creates an effective rate of 60 per cent – and on a year when assets decline, an effective rate of over 100 per cent. That creates an incentive to avoid the tax out of all proportion.' Tax rates set too high on savings mean that people are unduly encouraged to consume rather than make provision for their old age or any periods of unemployment, with dire long-term effects on the Exchequer and on economic growth. It might therefore not raise much revenue for long. Politically, it makes a government look desperate, as if it's constantly looking for new things to tax rather than getting the economy to grow.


The Independent
43 minutes ago
- The Independent
Reform defector left Tories after mayoral candidate selection row involving Theresa May's husband
Former prime minister Baroness Theresa May 's husband is involved in a row over the latest defection to Reform amid anger over candidate selection under Kemi Badenoch 's leadership. Ipswich based businessman John Howard, who was chairman of the Ipswich Conservative Association for a decade, had put himself forward to run as the Tory candidate for mayor of Norfolk and Suffolk next year. The property developer, who is a well known figure in local media, believed that his business skills and experience as an active member of the party made him a strong contender for the shortlist. But after an interview with a panel of two assessors, including Baroness May's husband Sir Philip May and head of the candidate committee Clare Hambro, he was rejected from a shortlist of five. Mr Howard told The Independent that the rejection was 'the last straw' for him as a Tory member having spent the previous five years 'trying to defend the indefensible', and he has now defected to Reform. He said: 'I have been trying to defend the indefensible for the last five years. 'Applying to be the candidate for the mayor was the final straw that actually made me realise that the Conservative Party do not listen to the grassroots. 'I'm aligned to really all the Reform policies as most Tory members are to be quite honest. And I think more and more are waking up to the point that actually Reform is the party of the future.' He described his conversation with Sir Philip and Ms Hamro as 'very pleasant', adding: 'I don't know if they were the ones to veto me.' But one senior Tory source said: 'I find it hard to understand why a candidate with a strong business background, good media performer and strong local routes would be rejected out of hand. The party has not learned from its failures that have brought us to the point of extinction. 'The trouble is that they want candidates who have no personality and can't think for themselves.' It is understood that Sir Philip only acts as an assessor for candidates, and is not on the committee which decides shortlists and selections. A Conservative spokesman declined to comment on the selection process and said its candidate for the mayor of Norfolk and Suffolk would be announced in due course. Another Tory source said Mr Howard had failed his assessment centre competency tasks.